Sewon Hur is a contributing author and former employee of the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland. Home; Profil. The conventional argument also does not say there will be no losers from trade. 97-100. [64] Lovely et al. “. The Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland and the Office of Financial Research hosted their annual financial stability conference, Financial Stability: Stress, Contagion, and Transmission, which was held virtually on November 19-20, 2020. “Americans Are Generally Positive about Free Trade Agreements, More Critical of Tariff Increases.” Pew Research Center, Krusell, Per, Lee E. Ohanian, Jose-Victor Rios-Rull, and Giovanni L. Violante. On the other hand, comparative advantage changes over time, and industry-region combinations which are economically strong now, may face rising competitive pressure as these changes occur. In good part, this also involves understanding the conditions and constraints under which firms operate, and what those conditions and constraints are in comparison to competitors abroad. The consequences of trade policies are also hard to predict. Like the best econometric models, the coefficients are related to one another independent of prices and exchange rates. 2019. Opening up to more of this sort of trade also leads to winners and losers at the firm level, with less efficient firms contracting (or going out of business) and the more efficient expanding (or entering the industry). The right-hand map of Figure 3 looks at which UK regions have been most subject to import competition from China over 2000-2015. First, changes in trade impacts differentially on regions depending on which industries/sectors are located where. [36], Having said that, losses in import-competing sectors and areas should be balanced against job gains due to increased exports. If we include industrial supplies and automotive vehicles, parts, and engines, the fraction rises to about two-thirds. Because of these last two channels, rather than restrict attention exclusively to imports, we analyze household expenditures on tradables, which in addition to imports also includes goods and services that either face substantive foreign competition or use significant shares of imported inputs in production. A high rate of labour market churning can imply greater uncertainty for workers through less job and wage security. Improved port facilities may increase local production because products are more easily (cheaply) sold abroad, or reduce it because imports that are substitutes for local production become more easily available. 2019. See for example, Fujita et.al. Although the … This is a phenomenon economists call “skill-bias”: workers with higher levels of education tend to benefit from higher levels of capital. As discussed above, the regional dispersion of any impact depends more on which import-competing industries are located where, such that we see a more substantial negative impact, for example, in the Midlands, or in Ayrshire and Lanarkshire. There is no obvious correlation between the two maps: the poorer TTWAs are not necessarily those that have been most exposed to import competition from China. Volkswagen), and these firms may well be located in different countries. By November 2018, the total US welfare loss was estimated to be $6.9 billion, or $1.4 billion per month. This is because the latter face more significant import competition from developing countries, and their inputs may be easier to replace and/or offshore. Evidence from Belgian manufacturing firms suggests that both Chinese import competition and offshoring to China resulted in considerable within-firm skill upgrading, with Chinese import competition accounting for 27% and 48% respectively of the total observed increase in the share of non-production and highly educated workers in low-tech firms. We first consider the impact of trade liberalisation on people, and secondly on places. A pair of last-year’s sunglasses may no longer be fashionable in one market, but sell extremely well in another market. Tim Worstall) have questioned that need. [62] West German cities close to the new border performed worse than other cities in West Germany because they lost half their traditional markets: they went from being at the centre of an integrated Germany to being on the periphery of West Germany. In interpreting this result, it is important to note that the size of the effects are measured as averages across certain income and wealth groups and so this does not imply that the magnitudes will offset for every household. Read More, The Fed is seeking to modernize the Community Reinvestment Act in a way that significantly expands financial inclusion, and you can have a say in how it’s done. 3. A worker’s skill level can also affect how his or her wage responds to increased trade. Source: UN Comtrade. Opening up to international trade (i.e. “, Carroll, Daniel R., and Sewon Hur. The driving force behind this was partly that manufacturing sectors, which were hardest hit by competition from China, were relatively more male labour intensive, and also that men faced relatively higher barriers to enter into services sectors compared to women. Then we turn to the price effects and highlight our own new research into how these benefits are distributed. [59] Similarly, the literature discussed earlier on the China effect also looks at which regions within countries (such as the US, France or UK) have been most exposed to import competition.[60]. For example, the tariffs introduced by the US and China in the on-going trade war have already impacted on prices, output and workers in both America and China.[12]. [12] See for example Amiti et al. (2001) and Gardiner et al. To shed some light on the answer to this question, in Carroll and Hur (2019) we quantify the price effect within a model and relate the magnitude of this channel to that of the labor market effect quantified in other papers. [26] Similarly UK manufacturing employment fell by 2.8 million over the period 1982-2018. (2019). The November 2017 issue of Page One Economics provides the ins and outs of trade, including some history, the costs and benefits, and policy choices. trade reflect factor-based distributional concerns,14 a number of studies link the expected winners and losers of global trade and financial flows to US international economic policy-making in Congress. [6] It is possible that the net effects of an act of trade liberalisation are negative, but the evidence suggests that this is rare. Thus, for example, government might seek to facilitate the acquisition of skills through education or communications by providing modern infrastructure. [18] In this they build on Feenstra and Weinstein (2017) who suggest that competitive disciplines is an important source of the gains from trade as well as of their distribution. We then summarise the empirical evidence on these mechanisms and discuss potential policy responses.[3]. Amiti, Mary, Mi Dai, Robert Feenstra, and John Romalis. The evidence shows that exporting firms tend to be substantially bigger, and may become more efficient through learning from export markets and international knowledge spillovers, and from importing higher quality intermediates, economies of scale, higher levels of investment, or from increased competition in export markets.[44]. Equally, it could increase the demand for some workers, e.g. Estimating US Consumer Gains from Chinese Imports, Trade and Labor Market Dynamics: General Equilibrium Analysis of the China Trade Shock, On the Heterogeneous Welfare Gains and Losses from Trade, The ‘China Shock,’ Exports and US Employment: A Global Input–Output Analysis, The Production Relocation and Price Effects of US Trade Policy: The Case of Washing Machines, What Are the Price Effects of Trade? First, consumers have the option to purchase imports from countries that produce at a lower cost. The views authors express in Economic Commentary are theirs and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland or the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. B) only the importer. [37] This is in contrast to the results discussed above for the US, and similar analysis for the UK. Some posit that the changes in trade were insufficient to have had such large effects, and that technological change was the more important driver, while others argue that trade was more important. In the CEX, we categorize an item as tradable if the percentage of the total output of that category represented by either exports or imports exceeds 11 percent.4 In the PSID, we categorize as tradable expenditures on clothing, food at home, prescriptions, home furnishings, the purchase and lease of cars and trucks, and a fraction of expenditures on entertainment, vacation, housing, and vehicle repairs. (2013, 2016) for US, Malgouyres (2017) for France and Foliano and Riley (2017) for UK. We study whether the forward guidance given with the April and June 2020 FOMC meetings altered the public’s expectations of future policy rates, GDP growth, and inflation. Over the past two decades the US economy has become more open to trade. In 2018, 56 percent of respondents to a Pew Research poll asserted that “free trade agreements between the U.S. and other countries have generally been a good thing for the U.S.,” while 30 percent claimed they had generally been a “bad thing” (Jones, 2018) [note: this citation was corrected after initial publication (was Bradley, 2018)]. “. Survival: Vol. In this Commentary, we have discussed how trade can affect households differently depending on their position in the labor market and the pattern of their consumption expenditures. We do so by documenting that the share of consumption expenditures that are tradable is higher for households with low income and wealth (Carroll and Hur, 2019). Bureau of Economic Analysis Table 2.1. Within industry effects arise because within any given industry there is substantial heterogeneity between firms, such as in terms of size and productivity. [68] See IMF (2017) for a discussion on policies to facilitate adjustment to trade. (2013) on Italy. In practice evidence suggests these programmes can be difficult for workers to access and are often under-utilised. Increased trade disproportionately lowers the costs of the bundle of goods and services purchased by a lower-income household compared to a higher-income household. It appears however, that successful adjustment assistance programs need to be easily accessible, flexible and encourage retraining and re-entry into labour markets as well as labour mobility.[71]. Evidence for Germany indicates that while import competing manufacturing sectors suffered job losses due to increased competition from China, this was more than offset by job gains in export-oriented manufacturing units who increased their exports primarily to Eastern Europe. Over this period, trade has increased dramatically as a fraction of GDP (figure 1). Skip to main content Accessibility help We use cookies to distinguish you from other users and to provide you with a better experience on our websites. There is some cross-country evidence that, for high-income countries, the gender wage gap tends to decrease with increased trade through a combination of a reduction in discrimination and an increase in the relative demand for female labour. [28] There is also some evidence, that while increased import penetration in final goods may negatively impact on manufacturing employment, increased imports of intermediates may have the reverse effect as it is associated with increased engagement in value-chains, and consequent exports of those goods higher up the value chain.[29]. The losers tend to be fewer and more concentrated, while there are typically many more winners but more widely dispersed. (2014) compares earnings and employment outcomes from 1992 to 2007 across workers with different levels of exposure to the rise in Chinese imports after China joined the World Trade Organization in 2001.2 Workers who had initially worked in industries with higher exposure suffered a difference in cumulative earnings equivalent to almost half of one year’s income relative to the earnings of similar workers with less exposure. Washington International Trade Association (WITA) Ronald Reagan Building and International Trade Center 1300 Pennsylvania Avenue, NW Suite G-329 Washington, DC 20004. wita@wita.org. Concomitantly, there were big changes in the levels and patterns of trade. See: House of Commons Briefing Paper (2018). Explain. (2000) suggest that this may be more advantageous for high-skill workers than for low-skill workers because these capital goods require skills to operate. The aim of this Briefing Paper is, therefore, to sketch out how trade changes may result in ‘winners’ and ‘losers’ – be these consumers, workers, regions, or industries. Daniel Carroll’s primary research interests are macroeconomics, public finance, and political economy. Cross-country studies show little evidence that trade liberalisation leads to a concentration of economic activity or regional inequality. [13] Alternatively if we look at specific sectors, trade in textiles used to be highly protected in the EU (and elsewhere) until the introduction of the World Trade Organization’s Agreement on Textiles and Clothing (ATC) in 1995. International Economics Globalization and International Relations. In a similar vein, a study of the impact on the UK of the EU’s Free Trade Agreements implemented over 1993-2013 finds a 26% increase in the quality of UK imports and a 19% reduction in quality-adjusted prices. For example, there is some evidence that offshoring to low-income countries, as well as increased import competition, contributed to some of the job losses, especially in low-wage, low-skilled (routine) occupations, and for older workers. Contrast this level of agreement with those from other polls of the EEP on. [63] Seven out of 14 within-country studies of spatial effects of trade openness look at Mexico. “, Caliendo, Lorenzo, Maximiliano A. Dvorkin, and Fernando Parro. In particular, all other things being equal, they benefit more when tradables’ prices fall in response to increased trade openness. Does anyone lose from international trade? “, Jaravel, Xavier, and Erick Sager. [43], The preceding examined changes in employment and wages across industries/sectors. While the tradable expenditure shares are higher in the CEX than in the PSID, the pattern is the same across both data sets. Briefly list five arguments often given to support trade restrictions. At its core, international trade is similar to the cafeteria exchange—both buyers and sellers trade because both benefit from the transactions. This section looks in more detail at some of the policy responses that could potentially help losers from international trade adjust, and ensure that the winners can take advantage of the new opportunities created by trade liberalisation. Not every single entity, however, gains from international trade. There are two related issues which are worth underlining. The effects from these two channels go in opposite directions: low-skill or low-wage households that are exposed to the most risk from labor market effects may also gain the most from less expensive tradables. [41] Technological change, and notably ‘computerization’, also helps to explain the increase in wages of skilled relative to unskilled workers in the US. “, Flaaen, Aaron B., Ali Hortacsu, and Felix Tintelnot. that more productive firms are more likely to export and can pay higher wages), or that the act of exporting leads to more wage inequality. [26] This was also a period with significant changes in trade, with the growth in Chinese exports, increased offshoring, and increased fragmentation of supply chains. [58] Those regions with the biggest increase in import penetration are in orange, and the darker the orange the greater the increase. This does not mean there are no gains from exporting. When it comes to the current trade practices, the general criticism is that there are winners and losers from free trades and that losers are not compensated adequately, farmers and labour groups fear that their incomes would get impacted and that bodies such as the WTO are biased towards corporate interests, environmentalists in general feel that not much is being done for the environment … (a) these goods may not be available from domestic sources. Generally, there are two principal justifications for policy intervention: market failure and equity. Finally, such policies favour producer interests, often at the expense of consumers who have gained from cheaper imports. If markets are in some way imperfect they will not generate the most efficient outcomes, and there may be scope for governments to intervene to address those ‘market failures’. (2016). Hiscox finds that legislator support for trade between 1824 and 1994 reflects the expected gains and losses experienced [49], Research on the impact of increased competition from China on the US gender wage gap indicates that the gains were higher for women than for men. [18], Finally, while consumers typically benefit from trade liberalisation, evidence supports the idea that low-income consumers tend to gain more because they tend to concentrate their spending in sectors that are traded more.[19]. Increased trade leads to lower prices through a variety of channels. We explore the electoral implications of the increasing tradability of services and the large US surplus in services trade. For example, the literature examining the rapid rise of Chinese trade, suggests that increased Chinese import penetration may have been responsible for about 1 million out of the roughly 6 million job losses in US manufacturing between 1999 and 2011. Workers in sectors particularly exposed to increased import competition tend to be adversely affected through job losses and falling wages, and some evidence suggests that the impact is felt more severely by low-income workers. This in turn can lead to negative spillover effects for example on crime, health and schooling. [8] This is sometimes referred to as ‘allocative efficiency’. Third, in a world of integrated supply chains governments should be careful to ensure that policy interventions do not disrupt those supply chains. One of them being the law of comparative advantage. Evidence from the US and Implications for Quantitative Trade Models, https://www.pewresearch.org/fact-tank/2018/05/10/americans-are-generally-positive-about-free-trade-agreements-more-critical-of-tariff-increases/, Tradable and Nontradable Inflation Indexes: Replicating New Zealand’s Tradable Indexes with BLS CPI Data, Capital–Skill Complementarity and Inequality: A Macroeconomic Analysis, Quantifying the Losses from International Trade, Capital–Skill Complementarity and the Skill Premium in a Quantitative Model of Trade. to estimate the effects of a free trade agreement once it has been in force for a period of time. Capital goods make up a significant portion of imported goods, about one-quarter (figure 2).3 Parro (2013) estimates that, for the United States, 14 percent of the change in the wage premium commanded by skilled labor from 1990 to 2007 was a result of a decline in trade costs. They can, however, still be used to shed light on who might be the winners and losers. A recent study on the welfare impacts of the 2018 US trade war with China shows that the burden of the US tariffs on China has so far fallen on US importers and consumers: the tariff increases have been almost entirely passed on through higher prices, rather than being absorbed by Chinese exporters. [50] Conversely, and perhaps counter-intuitively, the gender wage gap could widen when trade expands sectors which are relatively more female intensive, as appears to have been the case in the US following the introduction of NAFTA.[51]. We find that the difference in the price effect for low-income and low-wealth households and that for high-income, high-wealth households is of roughly the same magnitude as the difference in the labor market effect for similar households from other studies (Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro, 2019; Lyon and Waugh, 2019). There is less empirical work on this as it is perhaps more obvious that lowering trade barriers decreases prices and increases the range of goods and possibly also their quality. 2. This Commentary provides a review of the SRI’s performance from 2001 to 2020 and finds that it has performed well, providing a reliable, valid, and timely signal of elevated levels of financial system stress. This may be fostered by policies to address the factors that hinder the development of new activities and at times may also call for policy focussed on specific sectors. [6] Note that, typically, the gains are spread across many consumers, whereas the losses are much more concentrated – be this by worker type, industry or locality. [35], An important insight from these studies is that adjustment to trade shocks can be slow, and the costs largely fall on the trade-exposed local markets rather than being dispersed nationally, resulting in persistently low local labour force participation rates and high unemployment. [65] Evidence for the US suggests that, on average, for every 10 manufacturing jobs created in a US city there are 16 additional jobs created in the wider economy. citation courtesy of . The Cleveland Fed’s systemic risk indicator is one such measure. Read More, Wesley Janson
The impacts are complex, and in turn it means that there are no easy policy prescriptions. Such losses from trade are typically much more concentrated than the gains, which has fed concerns about the perceived disproportionate impact from trade, and globalisation more widely. Yet as Lindsey himself correctly observes, jobs and businesses in market economies are routinely destroyed even when international trade plays no role. [27] Such impacts will be felt in both manufacturing and services, and in both cases the losers are more likely to be the low-wage, low-skill intensive industries or occupations, and conversely for the winners. [72] This will affect what is traded, by whom and where and so may call for adjustment assistance. Winners and Losers: What is the Evidence? Second, even if markets are working well, societies may be concerned about the distributional implications, and hence desire intervention to ensure the gains from trade are spread more equally. Taking an even longer-run perspective, the 19th and 20th centuries witnessed the transformation of many economies from primarily agrarian to industrial. Within industry reallocations: In the preceding explanation, trade and the distributional impacts of trade, are driven by differences between countries (such as labour, land, capital or technology). Trade policy is inherently concerned with (economic) relations with other countries – be this tariffs, quotas or regulatory requirements. Autor et al. International Trade in Goods.” This is a conservative estimate. 4. In addition, if there are economies of scale in production, then it makes sense for some firms to concentrate on some varieties (e.g. We follow Johnson (2017) who finds that the 11 percent threshold minimizes the number of industries that change tradability classifications due to a 1-percentage-point increase or decrease from the threshold. Saying that trade has losers suggests that stopping trade would eliminate such losses. The study finds that the tariffs led to an increase in the price of washing machines, both foreign and domestically produced, commensurate with the size of the tariff. The wider evidence for developed countries suggests that low-income consumers benefit more from trade-induced lower prices than do high-income consumers because a higher share of their income is spent on traded goods. Trade policy can (and should) also form part of a broader industrial strategy. As a share of expenditures, poor households spend more on food, a relation known as “Engel’s Law.”. (2005). One way in which poor and rich households differ in their expenditure is on food consumption. The CRA Is Important for Underserved Communities, and Your Input Can Help Modernize It, 2020 Financial Stability Conference: Stress, Contagion, and Transmission, In the 2012 Economics Experts Panel (EEP), produced by the Initiative for Global Markets at the University of Chicago Booth School of Business, 94 percent of respondents agreed with the statement “Freer trade improves productive efficiency and offers consumers better choices, and in the long run these gains are much larger than any effects on employment.” The other 6 percent were uncertain. [32] Autor, Dorn and Hanson (2013, 2016); Autor, Dorn, Hanson, Song (2014). trade liberalisation) allows a country, and the consumers and firms in that country, to buy more goods from more countries. Here’s the data: 1. The direct impacts from changes in trade or trade policy on the spatial distribution of economic activity has also been considered in other contexts.